Making Sense - Sam Harris - May 22, 2020


#205 — The Failure of Meritocracy


Episode Stats

Length

59 minutes

Words per Minute

144.91426

Word Count

8,591

Sentence Count

399

Misogynist Sentences

7

Hate Speech Sentences

3


Summary

Daniel Markovitz's new book, The Meritocracy Trap, argues that the notion of meritocracy is flawed, and that any socioeconomic reward is based on a flawed notion of "self-made" rather than on "earned" wealth. In this episode, I speak with Daniel about why this is a problem that needs to be addressed, and how to fix it, and why it's time to move away from meritocracy and toward a new kind of caste system of "caste system" that rewards meritocracy but denies opportunity to people who are talented but don't succeed because they weren't given the right opportunities. The meritocracy Trap is a book that challenges the idea that there is a "right" way to achieve a meritocracy, and argues that there's no such thing as a meritocratic system at all. And that's why meritocracy should be replaced by a caste system, because meritocracy itself is unjust and unjustifies itself by being based on the notion that everyone should be given the same opportunities and a fair shot at the same things as everyone else. If you want to know how meritocracy works, then you need to start with the core problem, which is that there are no more talented people than there are talented people who succeed, because they don't have to be talented enough to succeed because of their meritocracies, because there are more talented than they were given enough opportunities to be given them the same chance to succeed. This is a conversation whose time has come and is overdue to be had, not a conversation that has come too soon, and needs to come to terms with the problem it needs to start. And so, I'll let you know what that means, and what it means, because it's come too late, and it's coming too late to get a chance to make sense of the problem, and too late too soon to start making sense of it and that it's a problem too late in the first place a problem whose time is now too late. Thanks for listening to the Making Sense Podcast? by Sam Harris Subscribe to The Making Sense by making sense? by clicking here to get access to the full episode by becoming a supporter of the podcast and getting access to future episodes of the show, and more episodes, and a discount on future episodes on the next one coming soon, coming soon so you won't want to miss it? and as always, I never want money be the reason why someone can't listen to the podcast?


Transcript

00:00:00.000 Welcome to the Making Sense Podcast.
00:00:08.460 This is Sam Harris.
00:00:10.380 Just a note to say that if you're hearing this, you are not currently on our subscriber
00:00:14.260 feed and will only be hearing partial episodes of the podcast.
00:00:18.320 If you'd like access to full episodes, you'll need to subscribe at samharris.org.
00:00:22.940 There you'll find our private RSS feed to add to your favorite podcatcher, along with
00:00:27.540 other subscriber-only content.
00:00:30.000 And as always, I never want money to be the reason why someone can't listen to the podcast.
00:00:34.940 So if you can't afford a subscription, there's an option at samharris.org to request a free
00:00:39.460 account, and we grant 100% of those requests, no questions asked.
00:00:49.020 Okay, well, today is a deep dive into wealth inequality and the underlying problem of our
00:00:59.660 notion of meritocracy.
00:01:01.760 Wealth inequality is something that I've been worried about for quite some time.
00:01:06.820 I think I first started speaking and writing about it in 2010, about a year or so after
00:01:14.260 the financial crisis.
00:01:16.200 I wrote a couple of blog posts.
00:01:18.000 I think the first was a New Year's resolution for the rich, and then how rich is too rich.
00:01:25.800 And it's come up a few times on the podcast before.
00:01:30.220 I never really questioned the norm of meritocracy, however.
00:01:35.980 And I haven't really thought much about the way our system of higher education has become
00:01:40.460 a perpetual motion machine of inequality.
00:01:44.400 But my guest today on the podcast has.
00:01:47.760 Today I'm speaking with Daniel Markovitz, and his book is The Meritocracy Trap, How America's
00:01:55.000 Foundational Myth Feeds Inequality, Dismantles the Middle Class, and Devours the Elite.
00:02:00.980 And Daniel is a professor of law at Yale, and as you'll hear, he's thought a lot about these
00:02:07.640 issues.
00:02:08.880 We talk about the nature of inequality in the U.S., the disappearance of the leisure class,
00:02:15.680 the way the rich now tend to work harder, at least as measured by time, than anyone else,
00:02:21.900 the difference between labor and capital as sources of inequality.
00:02:25.560 We talk about the shrinking middle class, the attendant deaths of despair in the U.S., we
00:02:34.080 talk about the different social norms among the elites and the working class, things like
00:02:40.080 out of wedlock, birth, divorce, etc.
00:02:44.360 We talk about the flawed notion of being self-made, and the illusion that anyone has earned their
00:02:51.220 advantages.
00:02:51.680 And we consider Daniel's proposal for a one-time wealth tax as a way of responding to the COVID-19
00:02:59.240 pandemic and its attendant economic calamity.
00:03:03.740 There's a lot here.
00:03:05.280 You might find it a little dense, certainly in the beginning, but I thought the conversation
00:03:10.640 was fascinating.
00:03:12.280 I learned a lot.
00:03:13.880 Looking back on my old blog posts of 10 years ago, and I noticed that in talking about the
00:03:19.580 consequences of automation and growing wealth inequality and people's resistance to redistribution,
00:03:28.520 I asked the rhetorical question, would anyone want to live in a country that has just minted
00:03:34.480 its first trillionaire and there's 30% unemployment?
00:03:38.900 Well, at the time, that was a cartoon example.
00:03:47.640 At the moment, that outcome is absolutely foreseeable.
00:03:52.880 We've certainly been pushed within range of that possibility by this pandemic.
00:03:58.960 So, that's just to say, this is a conversation whose time has come.
00:04:03.640 And now I bring you Daniel Markovitz.
00:04:14.360 I'm here with Daniel Markovitz.
00:04:16.160 Daniel, thanks for joining me.
00:04:18.220 Thank you so much for having me on.
00:04:19.520 It's a pleasure to be here.
00:04:21.020 So, you've written this fairly incendiary book, The Meritocracy Trap, and you also wrote
00:04:29.460 an op-ed in the New York Times recently that I want to talk about that is especially pitched
00:04:33.600 to this moment, but I really want to run through your entire argument here because it has the
00:04:39.240 virtues of being both quite consequential, you know, whether right or wrong, whatever we decide
00:04:44.240 about your argument, the consequences are enormous, and it's highly counterintuitive.
00:04:50.440 And so, I'll let you lay it out here.
00:04:52.320 But you've written a book really against this notion of meritocracy, and it's interesting.
00:04:59.360 This word was originally coined in a somewhat ironic or derogatory vein, but it was very
00:05:06.840 soon thereafter rechristened as an obvious norm.
00:05:11.780 And so, when we hear about meritocracy, you know, really for my entire lifetime, there's
00:05:16.480 never been a problem with it.
00:05:18.060 The problem has always been that we haven't actually achieved it, and the problem is that
00:05:25.260 there are people who are every bit as talented as the people who succeed, but they don't succeed
00:05:31.180 because they weren't given the right opportunities.
00:05:33.020 But you're arguing that the very norm of achieving a meritocracy is somehow flawed, and that any
00:05:39.740 socioeconomic reward that's based on this notion of merit is itself unjust and is leading
00:05:47.340 to a kind of new caste system.
00:05:50.640 So, perhaps let's just start with this core claim.
00:05:54.020 In what sense is meritocracy itself and the notion of merit itself the problem?
00:05:59.900 Sure.
00:06:00.300 So, let's start just by giving a quick and intuitive definition of what a meritocracy is.
00:06:08.480 It's when people get ahead based on their own accomplishments rather than on, say, their
00:06:14.060 parents' social class or their race or their gender.
00:06:17.900 And as you suggested a moment ago, it's very hard to object to that idea.
00:06:23.360 It seems like that idea would give a society a capable and competent and engaged elite, and
00:06:30.740 it seems like that idea would give everybody a fair shot at success.
00:06:34.120 And the early meritocrats, especially in the United States in the 1960s, and we can talk
00:06:40.280 about them in a little more detail later, very much embraced that thought.
00:06:44.900 They thought that meritocracy was a way of breaking established caste orders surrounding
00:06:50.100 heredity, breeding, race, gender, religion.
00:06:53.000 And for a while, meritocracy did function in that way, because natural talent is not the
00:07:00.360 property of any one race or gender or caste.
00:07:04.820 But then what happened is that the elite that was made by meritocracy, the people who themselves
00:07:12.200 got ahead by being really good at tests, really good at school, really hardworking, accomplishing
00:07:17.720 a lot, turned out to be incredibly good at training their children and to have an immense
00:07:25.080 appetite for investing in their children's education.
00:07:28.720 And they now so dramatically out-train and out-educate everybody else in society that not just poor families,
00:07:37.760 but middle-class families can't keep up.
00:07:40.620 And because education works, it now turns out that the people who, in this technical sense,
00:07:46.920 accomplish the most, who have the highest test scores, the best grades, are the same as the
00:07:52.020 children of the rich meritocrats of the previous generation.
00:07:56.100 And so in this way, what meritocracy has done is it was invented as the handmaiden of equality
00:08:01.500 of opportunity, but it's become an enormous obstacle to opportunity in the United States today.
00:08:08.160 I want to get into the problem specific to higher education and then the process by which
00:08:14.240 people seek to get into elite institutions, because that really is at the center of the
00:08:18.840 problem, at least on your account.
00:08:20.220 But before we get there, let's just talk about the nature of inequality.
00:08:24.760 I mean, just what is the status quo at this point?
00:08:28.420 And perhaps we should focus on the U.S.
00:08:30.840 I mean, I know this is a global problem, but within the U.S., you point out that we have
00:08:35.940 a kind of inequality that more resembles that found in a country like India than in a country
00:08:43.440 like France.
00:08:44.800 So give us a picture of what inequality is like at this point.
00:08:48.960 Yeah.
00:08:49.160 So we have two trends happening in the U.S. at the same time.
00:08:53.660 And I think one of the things that made the book controversial is that it emphasizes both
00:08:58.440 of these trends.
00:08:59.320 So one trend is falling poverty.
00:09:01.620 There's a lot of poverty in the U.S., and if you have my private politics, it's morally
00:09:08.160 unconscionable how much poverty there is.
00:09:10.020 There's more poverty than in other rich countries.
00:09:12.760 But although I think it's perfectly reasonable to think that poverty is the most morally pressing
00:09:18.300 economic issue of the age, it's not the distinctive one.
00:09:22.480 So the poverty rate in the United States today, depending on how you measure it, is between a
00:09:26.840 half and a fifth of what it was in 1960.
00:09:30.500 And 1960 is thought of by the left and the right both as a period of shared prosperity.
00:09:36.280 But poverty then was much, much deeper and wider than it is today.
00:09:40.580 At the same time as we have falling poverty in this country, we also have rising concentrated
00:09:46.440 wealth.
00:09:46.860 And the richest 1% of households in America today take home about twice as big a share
00:09:54.060 of national income as they did in 1960.
00:09:57.580 So you have both falling poverty and rising wealth.
00:10:02.180 And inequality has moved, as it were, up the income scale so that there is now more economic
00:10:08.180 inequality within the richest 5% of the population than in the population as a whole.
00:10:14.120 That is to say, the shrinking gap between the middle class and the poor dampens overall inequality
00:10:21.220 compared to the massively rising gap between the merely rich and the super rich.
00:10:27.340 And then there's one other thing that's going on that is also controversial or that I claim
00:10:31.900 is going on that's controversial, which is that the sources of the very top incomes have
00:10:37.260 changed.
00:10:37.720 So that by my calculation today, between two-thirds and three-quarters of the total income of the
00:10:45.040 top 1% doesn't come from capital, but rather comes from labor, so that the rich have become
00:10:51.860 the working rich or a superordinate working class.
00:10:55.420 Whereas for most of human history, if you wanted to know how poor a person was, you would
00:10:59.540 ask how hard or how long they work.
00:11:01.920 Whereas today, if you want to know how rich a person is, you ask how hard or how long they
00:11:06.140 work.
00:11:06.400 And that's also transformed the ideology of inequality in, I think, very damaging ways.
00:11:12.760 Yeah, there are many interesting distinctions in there.
00:11:14.960 So let's just take this one piece of the issue between disparities in work and in capital.
00:11:24.640 So your claim here is somewhat at odds with the much-celebrated thesis of Thomas Piketty, right,
00:11:31.880 that he published this book that everyone bought and I imagine few read a few years ago, where
00:11:37.640 he was arguing that because the gains that accrue to capital increase at a greater rate than those
00:11:44.160 that accrue to labor, the real driver of wealth inequality in first world societies, he wasn't
00:11:50.920 focused exclusively on the U.S., is the distinction between people who have capital, right, who have
00:11:56.640 investments and, you know, are therefore making money on their stock portfolio, say, and everyone
00:12:03.580 else who has to work for a living, you know, at any salary.
00:12:07.360 But you're saying that the truly rich here, first of all, they're not merely a leisure class.
00:12:15.180 I mean, this is not an episode of Downton Abbey we're living through.
00:12:18.360 They work harder, as measured in just time, than basically anyone else.
00:12:25.040 And that is the source of the most excruciating inequality, in this case, in the top, essentially
00:12:33.260 the Gini coefficient of the top 10%.
00:12:35.660 Right, right.
00:12:37.440 So let's talk just separately, briefly, about labor hours and then about the sources of income.
00:12:43.560 So in 1979, if you were in the top fifth of the hourly wage distribution, you were about
00:12:52.380 two-thirds as likely as someone in the bottom fifth to work over 50 hours a week.
00:12:57.240 By 2006, if you were in the top fifth, you were more than twice as likely as someone in
00:13:02.320 the bottom fifth to work over 50 hours a week.
00:13:05.020 So in the roughly 30 years at the end of the last millennium, the relationship between high
00:13:09.400 wages and long hours reversed.
00:13:10.840 It used to be the low-paid worked the long hours, and by 2006, the high-paid worked the
00:13:16.560 long hours.
00:13:17.860 And if you look at finer slices, between about 1940 and about 2010, the top 1% added, roughly
00:13:29.320 speaking, six to eight hours a week to its average workweek, whereas the bottom 60% lost
00:13:38.340 maybe eight hours a week from its average workweek.
00:13:41.680 So that's a shift of hours worked away from the bottom 60% to the top 1% of 16 hours a
00:13:47.680 week, which is two regulation workdays a week.
00:13:50.860 And I want to be clear, and I hope we come back to this, the reason why the middle and
00:13:56.140 working class aren't working such long hours is not that they're lazy and don't want to
00:14:00.220 work.
00:14:00.880 It's that the labor market has been restructured so there aren't enough jobs.
00:14:04.900 And even during our recent period of very low unemployment, we've also had very low labor
00:14:10.680 force participation.
00:14:12.120 So that it's true that not many people have been seeking work and not getting it, but many
00:14:15.760 people haven't been seeking work.
00:14:17.600 So that's the story of hours worked.
00:14:19.840 It's what sociologists of work call the time divide.
00:14:23.900 Then there's a separate story about where the rich get their income from.
00:14:27.740 And this is the point at which, as you suggested, Piketty's and my analyses depart.
00:14:35.080 Now, it's important to understand that both his effect and my effect could be going on at
00:14:40.840 the same time.
00:14:41.960 Yeah.
00:14:42.380 And that they'd compete only, as it were, on the margin of explanation.
00:14:46.980 So it could both be that those with capital are getting richer and also that those with super
00:14:54.260 skills and super labor are getting richer.
00:14:57.380 And the question is just which of these effects dominates the other in explaining the overall
00:15:02.080 rise of top incomes.
00:15:04.920 And it's important, actually, to read Piketty's book because Piketty himself makes quite clear
00:15:11.140 that in the United States, in contradistinction to Western Europe, until 2000, until 2000, top
00:15:20.160 incomes were driven by rising labor income.
00:15:23.840 So Piketty and I agree about that.
00:15:25.880 And the only place at which we disagree is what happened since 2000.
00:15:30.140 And we disagree there for two reasons, principally.
00:15:34.680 And I'm going to try to put the disagreement in a way that tries to be fair as between us.
00:15:38.580 And if we want to get into it, we can get into it.
00:15:40.320 But one question is, how should one categorize the income of the very highest paid workers
00:15:49.400 in management and finance?
00:15:51.980 So these are CEOs, top executives, hedge fund people, investment bankers.
00:15:59.580 Piketty inclines to categorize some portion of their income as capital rather than labor.
00:16:06.440 However, I view their income as labor income.
00:16:10.760 The reason why Piketty views their income as capital income is that he thinks, in effect,
00:16:14.700 that nobody's work could be worth that much.
00:16:17.160 And it's important to understand how much income there is here.
00:16:19.400 So in a recent year, the five highest paid employees of the S&P 1500, so 7,500 workers
00:16:27.440 overall, captured income equal to 10% of the total profits of the S&P 1500.
00:16:33.480 So these people are capturing quantities of income that matter macroeconomically.
00:16:40.700 I think of it as labor income because these are people who bring nothing but their own labor
00:16:47.860 to their employment contract.
00:16:50.600 They don't own the companies they manage.
00:16:54.120 The hedge fund people don't own the assets that they invest.
00:16:58.180 Instead, what they do is they sell their skills.
00:17:00.600 And I have a story about technological change that tries to explain why it is that,
00:17:06.140 counterintuitively, we've created an economy in which those skills could be incredibly valuable.
00:17:11.360 So that's one source of difference.
00:17:13.900 The other big source of difference is that I treat certain categories of pass-through income,
00:17:21.860 so this is income earned by people who own their own businesses,
00:17:25.520 and certain categories of capital gains.
00:17:28.980 This is income captured by people who invent things, start big companies, and have founder
00:17:34.580 shares as labor income, whereas Piketty treats it as capital income.
00:17:39.420 I again believe it's labor income because I think, once again, what these people are contributing
00:17:43.840 to the economic value of their ventures is their own ideas, their own work, their own labor.
00:17:50.520 And depending on how you look at the balance of these things, you get from Piketty's number,
00:17:56.100 which is that the top 1% get roughly half of their, little under half of their income from labor,
00:18:02.080 to my number, which is that the top 1% get between two-thirds and three-quarters of their income
00:18:07.280 from labor.
00:18:08.860 That's a material difference, but just to close this out,
00:18:11.220 the most striking difference is between either Piketty's estimate and mine, so either half
00:18:16.900 or three-quarters, and what was true in, say, 1910, when the top 1% would have gotten a sixth
00:18:24.080 or an eighth of its income from labor, or even 1960, the top 1% would have gotten a quarter
00:18:30.840 of its income from labor.
00:18:32.460 Right.
00:18:33.900 Well, maybe it's a distinction without a real difference, because the different norms around
00:18:39.240 work and time spent working are unaffected by how you class the source of income.
00:18:46.060 So you take somebody like, I don't know, Mark Zuckerberg.
00:18:49.420 I don't know Mark.
00:18:51.740 I've never met him.
00:18:53.200 I know many people know him, but I have no inside knowledge of his work habits.
00:18:58.060 But I would bet a fair amount of money that he works considerably more than a 40-hour
00:19:03.320 work week.
00:19:04.960 And also, his wealth is born not principally of his salary, whatever it is.
00:19:11.400 I would assume his salary is nominal.
00:19:14.160 It's a lot, but it's not $100 billion.
00:19:15.640 Yeah, it is nominal compared to his actual wealth.
00:19:18.740 And so he's making money based on the fact that he owns whatever it is, 20% of Facebook.
00:19:24.820 And so that's, you know, you could call that capital, or you could call that the returns
00:19:30.600 on labor.
00:19:31.700 But the reality is, he's almost certainly a workaholic, and therefore, very likely believes
00:19:40.500 that he deserves everything he's gotten.
00:19:43.320 You know, he didn't inherit this wealth.
00:19:45.980 He built it.
00:19:46.860 He created a, whatever you think of Facebook, an enormously influential piece of technology
00:19:52.300 that has attracted the attention of half of humanity.
00:19:57.360 And he's rewarded for that.
00:20:00.580 And he's, you know, part of the system you're describing in terms of the advantages accruing
00:20:05.020 to an educated elite to some degree.
00:20:08.400 I mean, he stepped off that hamster wheel pretty early.
00:20:11.400 He got to Harvard and then dropped out to start Facebook.
00:20:14.720 So on some level, this is part of your story.
00:20:19.060 I mean, although I guess you would probably view much of the success we see in Silicon
00:20:24.360 Valley to be a bit of a sideshow to your main thesis, right?
00:20:29.500 Because you're more talking about people who go the whole route through the academy and
00:20:36.700 come out and work for Goldman Sachs or in some context like that, where they're not reaping
00:20:41.880 these outside rewards based on their winner-take-all, one-off, brilliant idea.
00:20:48.160 They're actually part of a much larger system of credentialing and social signaling that becomes
00:20:54.860 this so-called meritocracy, where people are grinding away for, again, very long hours.
00:21:01.100 But I would imagine in the case of someone like Zuckerberg or any other founder like him
00:21:05.760 who's getting very rich, they may wish they didn't feel the need to work as much as they
00:21:11.260 do.
00:21:11.840 But many of these people are doing what they love or what they're addicted to.
00:21:15.640 They're not somebody who's several rungs from the top at a place like Goldman Sachs, just
00:21:21.560 being ground down by 90-hour work weeks because that's the way the machine runs.
00:21:27.540 So is there a distinction to make there, or is this basically that these are the same group
00:21:31.480 of people we're talking about?
00:21:33.400 Yeah, no, I think there is a distinction to make there.
00:21:35.000 Now, of course, there are lots of people now who go to work at Google or Facebook or Apple
00:21:39.900 or venture capital firms in Silicon Valley who are also working on other people's projects
00:21:46.280 rather than their own.
00:21:48.540 But your underlying suggestion about someone like Zuckerberg does generalize so that in
00:21:55.600 1984, for example, purely inherited fortunes outweighed self-made fortunes in the Forbes 400
00:22:03.720 by 10 to 1, but today self-made fortunes outnumber the inherited ones so that we've reversed even
00:22:11.520 there who thinks of themselves.
00:22:13.120 Now, self-made is a term of art, obviously, but it's different from being Zuckerberg from
00:22:17.720 being, say, one of the Koch brothers who inherited from their parents.
00:22:23.180 It's—I do think that there is an important political, psychological difference between
00:22:29.860 my view and Piketty's, and this, I think, also accounts for some of the controversy surrounding
00:22:37.200 the meritocracy trap, which is this.
00:22:39.020 The capital-intensive account of rising inequality focuses the blame for an inequality that most
00:22:48.020 people think is a bad idea at a group of people and a threshold wealth and a social position
00:22:56.040 that is different from the group of people who are the book's natural audience.
00:23:00.920 So the people who read Piketty are university professors, elite journalists, management consultants,
00:23:09.480 lawyers, doctors, the broad-reading elite, and Piketty's story absolves them of responsibility
00:23:18.440 for inequality, whereas my story says that them, namely me, us, and the institutions that
00:23:28.200 we serve and that have made us are at the very core of the machine that is producing more and more
00:23:35.620 inequality and blocking middle- and working-class people from opportunity.
00:23:40.520 And I don't know if that's a virtue or not of the theory, but it does explain why there's a way in which
00:23:49.060 a story like the capital story is quite comfortable for the elite left, whereas a story like my story
00:23:57.940 is quite uncomfortable for the elite left.
00:24:02.580 Yeah, that's interesting. And it's interesting to consider where these various tiers economically
00:24:09.720 should be drawn. I guess they could also be region-specific. I mean, what do you consider
00:24:15.380 middle class? What does the field consider middle class in general? And then how do you think about
00:24:22.540 middle class in a city like Manhattan or San Francisco?
00:24:27.720 Yeah, I think that's a good question. And it actually is a complicated sort of conceptual
00:24:34.680 question, and actually turns out to be a very complicated flat empirical question. So that often
00:24:41.180 people think of people as middle class as those between something like the 40th and the 80th percentile
00:24:48.280 of the income distribution. But of course, that varies by city and by region, and what it takes
00:24:55.260 to lead a certain kind of lifestyle varies very much by city. The practical or data complication there
00:25:03.140 is that there are lots of things in a city like New York or San Francisco that are obviously much,
00:25:09.180 much more expensive than elsewhere. Housing is a big example. Of course, private schools are another
00:25:16.180 big example. But then there are other features of elite or even upper middle class life that are
00:25:23.160 actually cheaper in New York City than elsewhere. So certain kinds of foods, certain kinds of
00:25:29.240 entertainment, certain kinds of restaurants are actually cheaper or easier to get in New York than
00:25:34.260 elsewhere. So it becomes quite complicated to figure out exactly what lifestyle bundle and at what price
00:25:40.880 it takes to be in the middle class or above the middle class socioeconomically. I tend to focus
00:25:48.100 on the top 1% and then the 4% that surrounds them in the sense that these are the 4% or the group that
00:25:56.540 credibly can claim it might one day be in the 1%. And so that's the group that I'm focusing the analysis
00:26:03.580 on. And that's partly driven by the fact that that's where almost all of the income growth in America
00:26:09.580 has happened over the past 30 years. So it makes sense to look at this narrow slice, although in
00:26:14.500 another sense, it's a very narrow slice. And focusing on them ignores distinctions between
00:26:20.180 somebody who's making $150,000 a year and somebody who's making $85,000 a year. Both are above median
00:26:28.700 household income, but they're in very different positions and neither of them is close to the 1%.
00:26:33.600 Right. Right. I think we should at some point drill down on the difference between the merely rich and
00:26:41.600 the super rich because those orders of magnitude are counterintuitive for people. And it's just
00:26:48.100 interesting to think about the significance of that kind of wealth stratification. It's odd to be
00:26:53.720 focused merely on the top 1%, but it's, you know, the difference between the 0.01% and the merely 1%
00:27:02.360 is so enormous at this point that you're not at all talking about the same thing. I mean, maybe we'll
00:27:08.480 save that for when we talk about your op-ed in the New York Times, calling for a one-time wealth tax,
00:27:14.680 because that's interesting. So is there more to say about the middle class here? You know, from
00:27:19.700 hearing your argument, it seems that the middle class is in some ways the hardest hit here. And I guess
00:27:27.440 in the context of the COVID-19 pandemic, there's additional concern that, you know, when we
00:27:33.960 surface from all of this, the middle class might scarcely even exist. What are your thoughts about
00:27:40.900 the middle class before we focus on the problems of wealth?
00:27:46.260 Yeah. So there's a sort of a straight empirical economic phenomenon, which is very striking,
00:27:52.900 which is if you ask about children's odds of becoming richer than their parents. So this idea
00:28:01.620 of sort of economic growth within the family lineage, that each generation is better off than
00:28:08.000 the one before. For the kids that were born in 1940, basically all of them were going to end up
00:28:17.320 richer than their parents. You had to get to roughly the 95th percentile of the income distribution.
00:28:22.900 Before children were not almost certain to become richer than their parents.
00:28:29.500 But for the group born in 1980, really only the poorest were certain to be richer than their
00:28:39.540 parents. And if you look at the drop in the chance of getting richer than your parents, so by how much
00:28:47.980 did that chance fall between 1940 and 1980, it fell by the most between the 30th and the 90th percentile
00:28:57.020 of the income distribution. So the broad middle class, if you think of people below the 30th percentile
00:29:04.620 as roughly speaking the poor, and people above the 90th as roughly speaking the rich,
00:29:09.940 the broad middle class had the biggest drop-off in its odds of becoming richer than its parents,
00:29:16.780 so that the sort of future-looking hope of the economy moved away from the middle class.
00:29:22.900 And at the same time, the charismatic center of the economy and the culture
00:29:29.900 moved away from the middle class. And this is not a flat economic phenomenon. This has to do with
00:29:38.040 how much housing costs. It used to be that a house in a really, really fancy neighborhood
00:29:43.660 would cost maybe two or three times what an average house would cost. Now it costs 20 or 30 times what
00:29:52.000 an average house costs. It used to be that in America, the most expensive car you could buy was
00:29:56.920 a Cadillac. It cost twice what a Chevy cost. Now there are lots of cars that cost 10 or 20 times
00:30:04.040 what the median car costs. The same is true for kitchen appliances. The same is true for meals out,
00:30:12.300 for bottles of wine, for which supermarket you shop at. It used to be everybody shopped at Safeway.
00:30:19.280 Now you can shop at Whole Foods or you can shop at Walmart, and they have very different feels, looks,
00:30:28.200 and products. One thing I looked into, the French Laundry, the California fancy restaurant,
00:30:35.060 and Taco Bell don't have a single ingredient in common.
00:30:39.700 That's hilarious.
00:30:40.480 Not even the salt. Not even the salt. What you're getting is a stratification of all parts of life
00:30:48.460 around this income divide. The part of life that captures the attention of the culture of the media
00:30:57.140 is the rich part, whereas it used to be the part of life that captured the attention of the culture
00:31:02.780 was the middle class part. And so that's another kind of demotion, now a sort of sociological,
00:31:09.120 cultural, psychological demotion for the same group that has taken the biggest hit in its economic
00:31:14.520 opportunities. And that's extremely damaging to flourishing and to politics.
00:31:21.140 Well, much of this is relative, of course, because as you point out, there's less poverty than there's ever been.
00:31:30.620 Right. And when you look at what the average lower middle class or even, you know, slightly below that person has access to
00:31:42.520 compared to, you know, what previous generations had, I mean, you just take something like a smartphone, right?
00:31:49.040 Well, it's just, this is a piece of magic if you brought it back to the, even in the late 20th century, right?
00:31:58.460 I mean, it's just, this is, you're walking around with something in your pocket that not even the president of the United States
00:32:03.980 had access to in the 80s or even 90s.
00:32:07.820 And I'm sure there are some technocrats or, you know, techno-utopians who would say there's nothing wrong with growing inequality per se
00:32:19.280 as long as the floor is rising for everyone. And there's some sign that the floor is rising for everyone.
00:32:27.280 What would you say to that?
00:32:29.240 Well, I think the first thing I say is that there's a sense in which what you say is even more true than your example suggests,
00:32:35.980 like the smartphone, you know, I don't know, did you ever drive a Chrysler K car?
00:32:42.920 No, I have not.
00:32:44.000 No. So, you know, a car in the 1980s, those were terrible cars.
00:32:49.740 Whereas a Toyota Corolla today is a great car.
00:32:53.680 Right.
00:32:54.380 It's safe, it's quiet, it's powerful, it's comfortable in a way in which almost no consumer good from 40, 50 years ago was.
00:33:02.940 And so it's not just new inventions, it's familiar things have become a lot better.
00:33:06.760 On the other hand, even though it is true that poverty is down and that middle-class consumption has continued to rise,
00:33:15.660 it's also true that other forms or markers of human flourishing have not been rising.
00:33:21.820 So if you think of Anne Case's and Angus Deaton's demographic work on the fact that there is rising mortality and falling life expectancy in middle-class Americans,
00:33:33.560 this is astonishing.
00:33:35.300 We have falling life expectancy in a group, a large group of the population, without war, without economic collapse,
00:33:49.040 and until six weeks ago, without epidemic disease.
00:33:53.740 And yet, life expectancies are falling.
00:33:56.500 And the causes of the falling life expectancy are overwhelmingly overdose, addiction, suicide, smoking, heart disease,
00:34:09.380 and other diseases associated with overeating.
00:34:13.300 They're forms of direct or indirect self-harm, really.
00:34:16.820 And the reason for that, I think, is that this goes back to the meritocracy point that we started with.
00:34:25.680 We've constructed a social and economic order with massive structural exclusion.
00:34:32.220 The reason it's hard to get ahead as a middle-class child or adult in America today
00:34:36.480 is that the system is rigged against you, the education system is rigged against you as a child
00:34:41.960 and rigged against your children.
00:34:43.140 The labor market requires you to have fancy training and fancy degrees that you can't afford to get.
00:34:49.360 And then meritocracy recharacterizes this structural exclusion as an individual failure to measure up.
00:34:57.360 It then says, and by the way, the reason you haven't gotten ahead is that you weren't good enough.
00:35:01.200 You didn't work hard enough.
00:35:02.160 You weren't virtuous enough.
00:35:03.240 And so the layering of this sort of profound moral insult on top of an economic injury
00:35:10.720 produces then the forms of self-harm that reduce life expectancy.
00:35:17.300 And the reduced life expectancy, which really is demographically unprecedented,
00:35:21.060 it just doesn't happen that you have lower life expectancy without war, disease, economic collapse,
00:35:28.800 shows just how damaging this form of exclusion and inequality really is.
00:35:35.900 And no amount of stories of better consumer goods or cell phones or even more square feet per person in housing
00:35:47.700 can make up for the harms done by that set of structural exclusions and moral insults.
00:35:55.360 Yeah, there are many differences in, just take this health distinction between the wealthy and even the middle class.
00:36:05.580 I think at some point you say that the life expectancy difference between the 1% and the middle class
00:36:11.660 exceeds what would be true if we cured cancer, which is a fairly arresting idea.
00:36:19.660 And there's just, there's so many other sociological differences in these cohorts.
00:36:25.180 I mean, you look at the rate of divorce or, you know, having children out of wedlock.
00:36:29.720 All of those things have enormous consequences too.
00:36:32.760 I mean, you know, divorce and having a child out of wedlock,
00:36:36.440 these are variables that are almost synonymous with economic hardship.
00:36:41.400 At minimum, a serious economic penalty and also an opportunity penalty with respect to the kids
00:36:48.960 and their ability to go to good schools and all the rest.
00:36:53.920 How else do you think about the difference in, there's a kind of a non-virtuous or virtuous,
00:37:00.300 depending on whether you're benefiting from it, cycle here.
00:37:03.000 Once things are going well, you know, everything tends to be going better.
00:37:07.400 However, how else do you think about the difference between the elites,
00:37:11.700 as I think you tend to call them, and everyone else?
00:37:15.140 Yeah, let me just say, first of all, the effects that you're describing are sort of so enormous
00:37:21.700 that if you don't look twice, you don't believe they're real.
00:37:25.760 So, you know, in 1970, out-of-marriage births accounted for less than 10% of the births to women
00:37:34.480 at all levels of education.
00:37:37.400 But today, women with a high school education or less, so without college degrees,
00:37:43.380 that's two-thirds of women, have over 50% of their children outside of marriage.
00:37:48.680 Whereas women with a college education or more have only 3% of their children outside of marriage.
00:37:54.300 Right.
00:37:54.480 So, this is not a small effect or phenomenon.
00:37:59.900 And I think the way I think about it is that life in capitalism,
00:38:09.460 and particularly life in a meritocracy, is hard.
00:38:14.340 It's a constant struggle in competition with others.
00:38:18.320 No institution or person gives you the basic things that you need to flourish without your
00:38:28.540 fighting to get them.
00:38:29.800 And that means that success under those circumstances requires enormous amounts of support early in life
00:38:42.480 and deep into adulthood.
00:38:44.460 And that support is incredibly expensive.
00:38:48.560 It's expensive in time.
00:38:50.080 It's expensive in money.
00:38:51.280 It's expensive in expertise.
00:38:52.580 And that means that grown-ups who are struggling themselves are not in a good position
00:38:59.740 to provide the advantages for their children that the children will need to compete in the next generation.
00:39:06.580 Whereas grown-ups who have abundance themselves are in a much, much better position to do it.
00:39:13.680 And that explains how inequality that in some sense looks like it's narrowly economic based on income or wealth
00:39:23.680 can become comprehensive, can reach into family structure, childbearing.
00:39:30.400 It reaches into religious practices.
00:39:32.960 It reaches into consumption practices.
00:39:35.080 It reaches into exercise.
00:39:37.960 You know, 80 years ago, prosperous was a euphemism for comfortably overweight.
00:39:45.260 Whereas today, the rich are almost exclusively extremely fit because they pay trainers and gyms to exercise.
00:39:55.060 Whereas the obesity epidemic that this country faces is overwhelmingly concentrated in the middle and working classes.
00:40:03.820 Again, expensive food is expensive.
00:40:08.700 And cheap, tasty food is cheap.
00:40:11.620 And so this is a way in which economic inequality can inscribe itself even in the bodies of the rich and the poor.
00:40:17.980 And it's extremely damaging to our broader social order.
00:40:22.220 Yeah, so on some level, there's changing norms here, which are also part of the problem.
00:40:31.820 It just takes something like fitness.
00:40:34.700 It once was the case that you could be obese and smoke a cigar and you're the caricature of a rich guy.
00:40:42.280 Now, if your midlife crisis entails training for an Ironman competition, you're the caricature of the super-driven CEO, i.e. rich guy.
00:40:55.300 But that's, you know, the money can be constant there.
00:40:58.580 We're talking about a new social norm.
00:41:00.680 So I'm wondering what you think explains that.
00:41:03.640 And also, I guess, I don't know the explanation for the change in out-of-wedlock birth.
00:41:08.840 But again, that's also another kind of norm here around sexuality, which it seems to me could at least be orthogonal to changes in objective economic circumstance and opportunity.
00:41:24.560 Yeah, I think it could be.
00:41:25.660 I think, in fact, they're not in the following sense.
00:41:31.060 If you live in an aristocratic system in which breeding itself, birthright, is sufficient to secure the success of children and keep the family dynasty going,
00:41:43.820 it doesn't matter very much how the aristocratic adults raise their children or spend their time, because their children will be privileged.
00:41:54.520 But in a meritocracy, one of the most important productive activities is training children.
00:42:04.240 And so one of the reasons why elite families live these hyper-conservative lives, although their official ideology around sex is one of great liberalism,
00:42:14.160 is that they realize that the success of their children depends on an orderly, work-driven, training-driven domestic space.
00:42:26.860 And so they produce it, and it has actually very bad gender effects within the rich families,
00:42:32.660 which is that rich women earn much, much less than their rich male partners,
00:42:39.500 even though the official gender ideology of the elite is one of economic equality between men and women.
00:42:45.680 On the other hand, the jobs that have been most attacked, most aggressively destroyed by the transformations in the labor market
00:42:56.880 that accompany this kind of inequality are the jobs that traditionally middle-class and working-class men did.
00:43:04.960 And so working-class and middle-class men have had their earning power most harmed
00:43:10.220 and their social status most harmed by these transformations in work and labor.
00:43:15.180 So that now, if you survey working-class families and households,
00:43:21.120 they say that it is important that husbands out-earn wives or that men out-earn women.
00:43:27.620 But in fact, in the bottom third of the income distribution, women out-earn men in households.
00:43:32.840 And this dramatically undermines the sort of ideology of marriage and domestic life
00:43:40.560 because, again, in a gender hierarchical society, this makes it hard to find marriageable men.
00:43:48.680 It makes men uncomfortable in households with wives who earn more.
00:43:53.080 And so when you overlay the form of inequality that we're seeing,
00:43:57.280 the economic inequality that we're seeing, on a gender hierarchy,
00:44:01.520 you get both extreme conservatism in the elite
00:44:04.880 and the breakdown of the traditional family outside of the elite.
00:44:09.260 And obviously, a lot of other things are going on at the same time,
00:44:11.840 and it would be crazy to try to reduce so complicated phenomena to this one line of explanation.
00:44:17.200 But it's not that the economic story has nothing to say about these wide social ramifications.
00:44:23.280 Yeah, that's really interesting.
00:44:26.680 So it seems to me we have a growing problem of social solidarity here,
00:44:32.680 and this has political implications that are increasingly painful.
00:44:37.020 And for me, just in private conversations in response to your recent op-ed on a wealth tax,
00:44:43.480 this was born home because, as you say in several places throughout your book,
00:44:49.200 the elite think of themselves as self-made, right?
00:44:52.860 I mean, now they're not, you know, by and large,
00:44:54.980 they're not people who just inherited their wealth from their grandfather,
00:44:58.680 who was a captain of industry.
00:45:00.820 These are people who got really busy very early
00:45:04.220 and have stayed busy up until about 30 seconds ago,
00:45:07.840 and they're being rewarded for it.
00:45:10.500 And they have had lives, in many cases, even most,
00:45:15.420 that, you know, by any measure have to be objectively granted as stressful,
00:45:20.180 but they've succeeded.
00:45:22.200 And so they are more resistant to redistribution
00:45:27.880 and any kind of ethical argument about its necessity or basic decency
00:45:33.000 than perhaps anyone.
00:45:35.860 And so I remember, so you wrote this op-ed in the New York Times
00:45:39.560 in response to the COVID pandemic,
00:45:41.580 and you argued that we need a one-time wealth tax.
00:45:45.400 Maybe just give me the potted version of that argument,
00:45:48.480 and then I can tell you what it was like to try to represent that in my world.
00:45:52.960 Sure.
00:45:53.520 So, you know, the pandemic is a systemic attack
00:45:57.400 on our economic and social life.
00:46:00.120 But it obviously hasn't hit everybody equally.
00:46:04.140 And unsurprisingly,
00:46:05.760 the richest and most educated people
00:46:09.780 are best able to socially isolate
00:46:13.420 and, in fact, best able to keep working
00:46:16.360 and to keep their jobs in the face of social isolation.
00:46:20.300 So if I think about my own situation,
00:46:22.200 I'm a university professor.
00:46:23.920 I've taught online.
00:46:25.540 I keep writing.
00:46:26.640 I keep working.
00:46:27.640 I keep getting paid just as I always would.
00:46:31.220 You know, it's a little stressful,
00:46:32.460 and it's not so nice to be at home all the time.
00:46:35.240 But basically,
00:46:36.480 this has not harmed me personally at all.
00:46:41.420 At the same time,
00:46:43.020 we have 30 million people newly out of work.
00:46:46.540 We have workers who were previously called low-skilled
00:46:51.060 now turn out to be recognized to be essential,
00:46:54.300 still working, in some cases,
00:46:56.040 being economically forced to keep working
00:46:58.180 in the face of the risk of getting sick.
00:47:00.240 And so what we've got is
00:47:03.040 a systemic attack on our whole society
00:47:05.480 that only the least privileged
00:47:09.300 are bearing the cost of.
00:47:11.600 And the thought behind the wealth tax
00:47:13.560 is that social solidarity
00:47:15.100 requires that everyone bears the cost,
00:47:19.660 and in particular,
00:47:21.300 that those who have most benefited
00:47:23.380 from this enormous run of rising inequality
00:47:26.500 should now give some back.
00:47:30.280 And it just so happens
00:47:31.740 that if you take 5% of the household wealth
00:47:36.460 of the richest 5% of households,
00:47:39.000 you get about $2 trillion,
00:47:41.240 which is just about what's been spent
00:47:43.200 on pandemic relief so far.
00:47:47.020 So these are round numbers,
00:47:49.240 and one should mistrust round numbers,
00:47:50.780 but there's a nice match
00:47:52.880 between a way of raising the money
00:47:57.180 and who credibly should be paying the money
00:48:00.900 out of a solidarity with the whole society
00:48:03.360 in the face of this really terrible thing.
00:48:07.640 And what's the significance of it being one time
00:48:10.240 as opposed to what was proposed
00:48:12.400 by the Warren and Sanders campaigns
00:48:14.640 to have an ongoing wealth tax,
00:48:16.940 which many people looked at
00:48:19.180 as either entirely unworkable
00:48:21.900 or still fairly onerous to implement
00:48:25.580 and the kind of thing
00:48:26.980 that would incentivize the offshoring of wealth
00:48:30.060 and just elaborate machinations to evade it.
00:48:34.280 Right.
00:48:34.460 So I think the logic behind it is different
00:48:36.660 and the implementation is different.
00:48:38.900 And you could favor both of them,
00:48:40.840 but you could favor them independently,
00:48:42.660 or you could oppose either of them
00:48:44.740 without opposing the other.
00:48:45.820 The logic behind this is shared sacrifice
00:48:50.320 in the face of a shared threat
00:48:52.040 or a collective threat.
00:48:54.740 And the logic of the Sanders-Warren taxes
00:48:58.420 were anti-oligarchy taxes
00:49:01.540 to rebalance our society
00:49:03.960 and increase the social safety net
00:49:06.440 in a steady state.
00:49:08.060 And so those are very different kinds of principles.
00:49:10.380 And I may actually privately in my politics
00:49:12.580 favor both of them,
00:49:13.840 but as I say,
00:49:15.440 the argument for one
00:49:16.220 doesn't turn on the argument for the other.
00:49:18.960 The different logic
00:49:20.200 means the taxes look very different.
00:49:23.020 The Sanders-Warren taxes
00:49:24.040 kick in in the top 0.1%.
00:49:26.140 Households whose aggregate wealth
00:49:28.320 was in one case $32 million
00:49:29.980 and in another case over $50 million.
00:49:33.380 These are very rich people
00:49:34.660 and they're ongoing taxes.
00:49:36.100 The tax I propose
00:49:38.060 would hit the whole of the top 5%.
00:49:40.860 So these are households
00:49:42.400 with household wealth
00:49:43.180 over $2.5 million.
00:49:44.820 Although it would exclude
00:49:46.320 the first $2.5 million.
00:49:48.220 So if your wealth were $2.6 million,
00:49:50.400 you'd pay the tax
00:49:51.280 on only the last $100,000.
00:49:53.520 That means that the tax
00:49:55.020 that I'm proposing
00:49:56.020 raises a lot more revenue,
00:49:58.020 is a lot harder to avoid,
00:50:00.200 and because it's only one time,
00:50:02.080 you can't plan your affairs to avoid it.
00:50:03.980 So it's much easier to implement.
00:50:07.060 And as I say,
00:50:08.820 it solves a pressing current
00:50:11.720 politico-social problem
00:50:14.860 of solidarity in the face of this,
00:50:18.280 which is, again,
00:50:19.200 very different from the logic
00:50:20.280 of the ongoing taxes.
00:50:22.800 Okay, so there are a few things
00:50:24.520 that one encounters
00:50:25.660 in trying to shill
00:50:27.720 for your noble thesis here.
00:50:30.540 I didn't workshop this
00:50:32.080 among many people,
00:50:32.760 but there are a couple
00:50:34.000 of fairly well-off people
00:50:36.640 I pitched this to
00:50:38.280 because I immediately
00:50:39.540 took a liking to this idea
00:50:41.920 for two reasons.
00:50:43.460 One, it's somebody's going
00:50:44.720 to have to pay
00:50:45.380 for this bailout eventually.
00:50:48.240 I mean, it can't be
00:50:49.280 all a matter of printing money.
00:50:51.360 But two, this notion
00:50:53.180 of shared sacrifice,
00:50:54.100 and I'm acutely aware
00:50:56.100 of the disparities here.
00:50:57.800 But one thing you encounter
00:51:00.700 in recommending a one-time wealth tax
00:51:03.960 is that these disparities
00:51:06.160 are fairly galling
00:51:09.640 even among wealthy people
00:51:12.660 because just by sheer accident,
00:51:15.920 some wealthy people
00:51:16.940 or even not-so-wealthy people
00:51:18.860 are entirely spared
00:51:20.660 by the pandemic
00:51:22.720 just because they happen
00:51:23.720 to be in a business
00:51:24.860 that is either untouched
00:51:27.080 or even improved
00:51:28.620 by it, right,
00:51:29.880 in some cases.
00:51:31.020 And then there are other people
00:51:31.980 who are or were
00:51:33.840 quite wealthy
00:51:34.680 who are just getting crushed
00:51:37.080 because there's no possibility
00:51:38.480 of working from home
00:51:39.640 in their industry, right?
00:51:40.600 If they're making cars
00:51:42.320 or airplanes
00:51:43.140 or whatever it is,
00:51:44.420 you can't do any of that
00:51:45.460 from home
00:51:45.980 and everything is ground
00:51:47.660 to a halt.
00:51:48.740 Or if you're,
00:51:50.200 you know,
00:51:50.600 Disney is a fantastically
00:51:51.860 wealthy company
00:51:53.820 and its top executives
00:51:55.900 are extremely wealthy
00:51:57.360 but they have way more exposure
00:52:00.240 to the pandemic
00:52:01.000 given their reliance
00:52:02.720 on their theme parks
00:52:04.780 and other real-world venues, right?
00:52:08.080 And so you have
00:52:08.840 some analogous company
00:52:10.100 that has none of those exposures
00:52:12.500 and is doing fine.
00:52:14.080 And so there's a story
00:52:16.500 to be told
00:52:17.040 about good and bad luck
00:52:18.400 even among the wealthy
00:52:20.400 and to try to implement
00:52:22.660 a wealth tax.
00:52:23.680 I mean,
00:52:23.820 you start the clock ticking
00:52:25.560 eight weeks ago
00:52:26.880 and you say,
00:52:27.640 who was wealthy
00:52:28.680 eight weeks ago?
00:52:29.500 Okay, now give us
00:52:30.160 five percent of your money.
00:52:31.760 That is something
00:52:32.960 from which
00:52:34.060 at least some of these
00:52:35.020 wealthy people recoil.
00:52:36.440 What do you,
00:52:36.780 how do you think about that?
00:52:37.840 Yeah, I think that
00:52:38.500 you raise
00:52:39.300 two good points
00:52:40.620 and they're
00:52:41.100 two different points
00:52:42.980 and I want to respond
00:52:44.520 to them differently.
00:52:46.160 The second point
00:52:47.340 is that there
00:52:48.120 may be some people
00:52:49.260 who appeared
00:52:50.100 wealthy
00:52:51.060 eight weeks ago
00:52:52.880 but in fact
00:52:53.840 are no longer
00:52:54.340 so wealthy
00:52:54.860 and those are people
00:52:57.440 who've already borne
00:52:58.540 a real cost
00:52:59.740 from this pandemic
00:53:01.220 and on my view...
00:53:03.580 Although,
00:53:03.820 if I can sharpen it up,
00:53:05.020 Daniel,
00:53:05.240 I would add
00:53:05.920 that some of these people
00:53:06.740 are certainly still wealthy
00:53:08.280 right now on paper
00:53:09.580 but they are right
00:53:12.360 to believe
00:53:12.880 that they're in a circumstance
00:53:15.100 of far greater uncertainty
00:53:17.140 than some other wealthy person
00:53:19.340 for whom
00:53:20.220 the prospects
00:53:21.380 of an ongoing pandemic
00:53:22.660 don't spell
00:53:24.240 any analogous doom.
00:53:25.940 Yeah, sure.
00:53:26.740 Sure.
00:53:27.060 No, I get that.
00:53:28.000 You know,
00:53:28.460 the answer I want to give
00:53:30.280 though still remains
00:53:31.200 that
00:53:31.520 the exemption
00:53:33.060 of two and a half million dollars
00:53:34.420 of household wealth
00:53:35.400 means that
00:53:37.660 from the perspective
00:53:39.060 of the average American,
00:53:42.040 everybody who pays the tax
00:53:43.440 is really rich
00:53:44.080 and that matters
00:53:46.940 I think
00:53:47.940 and it's true
00:53:48.900 that some people
00:53:50.200 are not as rich
00:53:50.860 as they were
00:53:51.480 and some people
00:53:52.560 are suffering
00:53:54.120 real setbacks
00:53:55.040 but yet
00:53:56.300 they remain
00:53:57.000 really rich
00:53:57.780 from the perspective
00:53:58.540 of the average American.
00:54:00.380 Now,
00:54:00.740 that doesn't go
00:54:01.860 to the first thing
00:54:02.920 you said
00:54:03.340 which is that
00:54:04.060 there is tremendous
00:54:05.700 inequality,
00:54:08.860 differential luck
00:54:09.780 and even deep unfairness
00:54:11.580 within the group
00:54:13.120 of the rich.
00:54:14.080 and some people
00:54:16.040 as you say
00:54:16.520 have benefited from this
00:54:17.760 some people
00:54:18.600 have been burdened by it
00:54:20.380 some people
00:54:21.640 are merely rich
00:54:23.360 some people
00:54:23.920 are super duper rich
00:54:25.200 and this tax
00:54:26.420 doesn't really
00:54:26.960 distinguish between them
00:54:28.360 as aggressively
00:54:29.340 as it might
00:54:30.020 and there
00:54:32.360 I really have
00:54:33.560 sort of a piece
00:54:34.340 of political psychology
00:54:36.860 or political ethics
00:54:38.000 as an answer
00:54:38.660 and people will either
00:54:39.520 find it moving
00:54:40.440 or not
00:54:41.420 but
00:54:42.620 one of the things
00:54:44.660 it means
00:54:45.320 for us all
00:54:46.020 to be in this together
00:54:47.260 as a society
00:54:48.660 and a country
00:54:49.440 is that
00:54:51.920 we don't
00:54:52.800 look on
00:54:54.520 each other
00:54:55.740 one at a time
00:54:58.000 and ask
00:54:58.820 who has more
00:54:59.820 rather
00:55:01.780 we ask
00:55:02.560 do we have
00:55:04.180 more
00:55:04.820 than is fair
00:55:06.240 for us
00:55:06.960 to have
00:55:07.640 and
00:55:09.700 I think
00:55:10.520 the answer
00:55:10.960 to that question
00:55:11.780 for the broad
00:55:12.660 group of people
00:55:13.440 that this tax
00:55:14.220 would
00:55:14.600 raise its revenue
00:55:16.020 from
00:55:16.400 again
00:55:16.920 these are
00:55:17.240 households
00:55:17.580 with wealth
00:55:18.220 over two and a half
00:55:19.560 million dollars
00:55:20.400 is yes
00:55:21.780 all of us
00:55:23.120 in that group
00:55:23.880 have more
00:55:24.900 than is fair
00:55:25.480 for us to have
00:55:26.260 and maybe
00:55:27.720 some of us
00:55:28.460 have even
00:55:29.640 more
00:55:29.920 more
00:55:30.200 than others
00:55:30.860 and maybe
00:55:31.260 there are
00:55:31.580 unfairnesses
00:55:32.340 within our
00:55:32.880 group
00:55:33.200 but
00:55:34.760 in the face
00:55:36.740 of a
00:55:37.520 national calamity
00:55:38.700 we shouldn't
00:55:40.400 focus on
00:55:40.980 those
00:55:41.620 and maybe
00:55:42.400 there's an
00:55:42.880 analogy here
00:55:43.800 actually
00:55:44.240 to war
00:55:45.360 which is
00:55:45.880 that
00:55:46.140 we try
00:55:47.280 to have
00:55:47.460 a fair
00:55:47.900 kind of
00:55:48.320 draft
00:55:48.820 in
00:55:49.420 an
00:55:50.140 existential
00:55:50.620 war
00:55:51.140 and then
00:55:52.220 we understand
00:55:52.700 that once
00:55:53.080 you're
00:55:53.220 drafted
00:55:53.580 some
00:55:54.860 people
00:55:55.160 get
00:55:56.260 bad luck
00:55:56.920 and have
00:55:57.380 an
00:55:57.600 unfair
00:55:58.340 assignment
00:55:58.940 but
00:55:59.940 that doesn't
00:56:01.240 give them
00:56:01.920 a complaint
00:56:02.580 against those
00:56:03.640 who got
00:56:04.040 a luckier
00:56:04.520 assignment
00:56:05.060 as long
00:56:06.300 as the
00:56:06.640 basic
00:56:06.900 system
00:56:07.380 is fair
00:56:07.900 and
00:56:08.880 that's
00:56:09.460 what
00:56:09.660 this
00:56:10.160 tax
00:56:10.500 is
00:56:10.660 trying
00:56:10.900 to do
00:56:11.260 is to
00:56:11.580 say
00:56:11.780 those
00:56:12.120 who
00:56:12.280 are
00:56:12.400 most
00:56:12.660 privileged
00:56:13.160 as a
00:56:13.680 group
00:56:14.000 owe
00:56:14.840 something
00:56:15.140 to
00:56:15.340 society
00:56:15.880 and
00:56:16.880 we
00:56:17.240 shouldn't
00:56:18.500 quibble
00:56:18.920 amongst
00:56:19.340 ourselves
00:56:19.880 about
00:56:20.260 which
00:56:20.520 ones
00:56:20.780 of us
00:56:21.040 owe
00:56:21.180 the
00:56:21.340 most
00:56:21.680 and
00:56:22.260 that's
00:56:22.440 another
00:56:22.660 way
00:56:22.900 in a way
00:56:23.260 which
00:56:23.480 is
00:56:23.640 different
00:56:24.080 from
00:56:24.440 the
00:56:24.720 Sanders
00:56:25.780 Warren
00:56:26.120 taxes
00:56:26.600 which
00:56:27.460 are
00:56:27.620 trying
00:56:27.980 to
00:56:28.260 get
00:56:28.900 the
00:56:29.200 fairness
00:56:29.540 right
00:56:30.060 all
00:56:30.400 the way
00:56:30.660 up
00:56:30.820 the
00:56:30.980 scale
00:56:31.300 at
00:56:31.500 every
00:56:31.740 moment
00:56:32.160 rather
00:56:32.980 than
00:56:33.220 trying
00:56:33.520 to
00:56:34.340 express
00:56:35.040 meaningful
00:56:35.800 solidarity
00:56:36.500 in a
00:56:36.840 moment
00:56:37.040 of
00:56:37.200 crisis
00:56:37.560 I don't
00:56:39.080 know if
00:56:39.220 you find
00:56:39.420 that
00:56:39.560 persuasive
00:56:39.960 or not
00:56:40.280 but that's
00:56:40.820 the kind
00:56:41.400 of thinking
00:56:41.740 that I
00:56:42.320 have in
00:56:42.580 mind
00:56:42.880 yeah
00:56:44.700 I
00:56:44.940 think
00:56:45.360 many
00:56:46.140 people
00:56:46.640 certainly
00:56:47.640 many
00:56:47.880 rich
00:56:48.140 people
00:56:48.460 and
00:56:48.660 even
00:56:48.920 many
00:56:49.600 people
00:56:49.860 who
00:56:50.000 merely
00:56:50.460 aspire
00:56:50.880 to
00:56:51.040 be
00:56:51.160 rich
00:56:51.440 will
00:56:52.100 grow
00:56:52.440 worried
00:56:52.980 over
00:56:53.240 this
00:56:53.500 notion
00:56:53.940 of
00:56:54.400 just
00:56:55.500 how
00:56:55.740 much
00:56:56.120 wealth
00:56:56.900 it's
00:56:57.360 fair
00:56:57.860 for a
00:56:58.280 person
00:56:58.540 to
00:56:58.720 have
00:56:59.120 because
00:56:59.880 first
00:57:00.360 of all
00:57:00.580 you're
00:57:01.100 being
00:57:01.540 agnostic
00:57:02.080 as to
00:57:02.440 how they
00:57:02.780 came
00:57:03.100 by that
00:57:03.480 wealth
00:57:03.780 I
00:57:03.920 mean
00:57:03.980 there's
00:57:04.180 certainly
00:57:05.720 a
00:57:05.960 libertarian
00:57:06.700 fantasy
00:57:07.900 that
00:57:08.980 it's
00:57:09.760 impossible
00:57:10.180 to get
00:57:10.740 truly
00:57:11.420 wealthy
00:57:11.860 without
00:57:12.400 creating
00:57:13.380 commensurate
00:57:14.220 value
00:57:14.740 for people
00:57:15.400 that the
00:57:15.820 wealth
00:57:16.140 that a
00:57:16.380 person
00:57:16.620 accrues
00:57:17.160 is
00:57:17.620 merely
00:57:18.420 synonymous
00:57:19.040 with
00:57:19.740 the degree
00:57:20.900 to which
00:57:21.160 they have
00:57:21.460 benefited
00:57:21.980 other
00:57:22.380 people
00:57:22.780 very
00:57:23.500 directly
00:57:23.880 in their
00:57:24.200 lives
00:57:24.660 and
00:57:25.120 the
00:57:26.040 metric
00:57:26.620 of that
00:57:27.080 is
00:57:27.380 all
00:57:27.880 these
00:57:28.120 people
00:57:28.500 you know
00:57:28.820 in
00:57:29.140 the
00:57:29.580 cases
00:57:29.840 of the
00:57:30.100 truly
00:57:30.300 wealthy
00:57:30.660 people
00:57:31.060 by the
00:57:31.460 millions
00:57:31.880 have
00:57:32.880 literally
00:57:33.500 opened
00:57:33.860 their
00:57:34.060 wallets
00:57:34.580 to
00:57:34.920 them
00:57:35.180 because
00:57:35.680 they
00:57:36.020 found
00:57:36.280 so much
00:57:36.580 value
00:57:36.960 in what
00:57:37.320 they
00:57:37.460 produced
00:57:37.860 we
00:57:38.580 can
00:57:38.860 certainly
00:57:39.720 find
00:57:40.320 examples
00:57:40.860 of
00:57:41.200 you know
00:57:41.960 rent
00:57:42.280 seeking
00:57:42.640 and
00:57:43.120 parasitic
00:57:44.040 economic
00:57:44.800 behavior
00:57:45.240 that doesn't
00:57:45.860 seem to be
00:57:46.340 creating much
00:57:46.920 value for
00:57:47.500 anyone
00:57:47.820 or if it
00:57:48.700 is creating
00:57:49.060 value
00:57:49.480 it's very
00:57:49.880 hard to
00:57:50.420 discern what
00:57:51.360 that value
00:57:51.840 is or how
00:57:52.460 it touches
00:57:52.840 the life
00:57:53.260 of any
00:57:53.640 individual
00:57:54.140 and these
00:57:55.640 people are
00:57:55.960 growing
00:57:56.180 fantastically
00:57:56.800 wealthy
00:57:57.180 so I
00:57:58.220 think there
00:57:58.480 are people
00:57:58.720 who would
00:57:59.080 fall outside
00:57:59.980 that analysis
00:58:00.760 but in
00:58:01.680 the case
00:58:01.980 of someone
00:58:02.360 who has
00:58:02.820 just
00:58:03.220 created a
00:58:04.380 brilliant
00:58:04.700 product
00:58:05.280 that everyone
00:58:06.060 on earth
00:58:06.560 wants
00:58:07.140 I think
00:58:08.020 most people's
00:58:09.000 certainly most
00:58:09.840 Americans
00:58:10.440 core
00:58:11.520 ethical
00:58:12.400 intuition
00:58:12.800 here is
00:58:13.440 you know
00:58:14.120 that person
00:58:14.580 deserves
00:58:15.340 he or she
00:58:16.100 deserves
00:58:16.820 to get
00:58:17.880 as wealthy
00:58:18.580 as they
00:58:18.980 possibly can
00:58:20.040 based on
00:58:21.560 having created
00:58:22.240 that value
00:58:22.800 the sky is
00:58:23.740 the limit
00:58:24.060 and it doesn't
00:58:24.560 even matter
00:58:25.140 if it's
00:58:25.540 something
00:58:25.820 if it's
00:58:26.760 something
00:58:26.960 if it's
00:58:27.540 something
00:58:28.880 if you'd like
00:58:29.640 to continue
00:58:30.060 listening to this
00:58:30.660 podcast
00:58:31.200 you'll need to
00:58:32.020 subscribe at
00:58:32.700 samharris.org
00:58:33.640 you'll get access
00:58:34.680 to all full-length
00:58:35.740 episodes of the
00:58:36.440 Making Sense podcast
00:58:37.220 and to other
00:58:38.220 subscriber-only content
00:58:39.480 including bonus
00:58:40.540 episodes
00:58:41.160 and AMAs
00:58:42.080 and the
00:58:42.820 conversations
00:58:43.280 I've been having
00:58:43.880 on the
00:58:44.120 Waking Up app
00:58:44.760 the Making Sense
00:58:46.100 podcast is ad-free
00:58:47.220 and relies entirely
00:58:48.580 on listener support
00:58:49.440 and you can
00:58:50.420 subscribe now
00:58:51.160 at samharris.org
00:59:06.440 to the
00:59:13.520 you
00:59:14.380 can
00:59:16.440 share